❗Let's close the gap: We still need your help to raise $40,000 by April 1. Donate now
Shelf Life

Robert Reich is trying to save capitalism

Kai Ryssdal Sep 29, 2015
HTML EMBED:
COPY
Shelf Life

Robert Reich is trying to save capitalism

Kai Ryssdal Sep 29, 2015
HTML EMBED:
COPY

Because we are already well into the election season, we’re going to keep hearing about our economic system, and the wonders and the downfalls of capitalism. 

The latest book from Robert Reich, former Secretary of Labor under President Clinton and a former regular commentator on this show, is all about that. In his book Saving Capitalism: for the Many, Not the Few,” Reich argues that the rules of the game should be tweaked to help fight against economic inequality. 

On the ways capitalism is broken:

Look, it is broken in the sense that median wages, as you know, have been stagnant for about 30 years adjusted for inflation, almost all the economic gains have gone to the top. Inequality is widening, a lot of Americans are working harder than ever, they’re not going anywhere and we have a lot of people called the working poor, who are working full time and are still poor. So there’s a lot that’s not going quite well and I think that if we don’t get serious about changing the rules of the game … we’re going to find ourselves with a capitalism that really is fundamentally not working for our people.

On when capitalism broke:

I think between 1946 and 1980 we had one kind of capitalism, it was a capitalism that worked for most people. If you worked hard you are going to do better, your children were going to do better than you. One member of the household needed to work and you could still do well. And then starting in 1980, ’81, ’82 you really see something change. The median wage stagnates, it flattens, for most people it actually goes down adjusted for inflation, household income starts flattening as well. Most of the gains go to the top and there’s much much more economic insecurity wherever you look. I mean pensions go from defined benefits, to defined contributions, and then they go to do it yourself pensions and everywhere you look in the economy it becomes less secure.

On decline of unions and other popular organization:

In contrast to the fifties and sixties, let me take you back on a little journey in time and you find that the genius of the system. We didn’t just have big banks, big businesses and big corporations, we had those things, but we also had countervailing power centers. We had state banks and local banks, we labor unions, we had farm cooperatives — not just big agriculture, we had a lot of economic organizations in our society that balanced out and countervailed against those big powers and so that we, in coming up with the rules of the game, could come up with rules that benefited everybody instead of those just at the top. That countervailing power started to disintegrate in the late ’70s and early ’80s and now we have very little of it.

On what’s worth saving:

I want to preserve the basic principles, which are private property and voluntary exchange. I mean, those are what we have inherited and really works very well, much better than communism. Even China has adopted a lot of capitalism. You can’t find any successful economy in the world that hasn’t adopted those principles. But you’ve got to make it work for average people, you’ve got to keep the trust of the people in the system, and right now if you look at every poll and ask people, “Well is the system working for you?,” most people say no. “Do you think it’s rigged for the benefit of the people at the top?” “Yes.” And this undermines the public trust in it, it kind of invites all sorts of pilfering and corruption and, “I’m gonna get mine and to hell with everybody else.”

On the costs of saving capitalism:

Obviously there’s going to be some sacrifice and some pain. We can’t really retool the system and make it work for everyone unless there is some sacrifice, but think of the alternative. The alternative is that we have an economy that is working for a smaller and smaller and smaller number of people. Look at politics these days, the 2016 election is really being dominated by voices of people who are not from what might be called the ruling class of America. I mean whether you like Donald Trump or not, or you like Bernie Sanders or not, they represent a kind of rejection of the way things had been going, and I think most Americans are saying we don’t want to continue in the direction, the way things have been going.

Produced by Tommy Andres and Bridget Bodnar. Web elements produced by Tony Wagner and Kevin Truong.

Hear much more, including how Reich’s own family background informed his view, in the audio player above. Read an excerpt from “Saving Capitalism” below.


1

The Prevailing View

It usually occurs in a small theater or a lecture hall. Someone introduces me and then introduces a person who is there to debate me. My debate opponent and I then spend five or ten minutes sparring over the chosen topic—education, poverty, income inequality, taxes, executive pay, middle-class wages, climate change, drug trafficking, whatever. It doesn’t matter. Because, with astounding regularity, the debate soon turns to whether the “free market” is better at doing something than government.

I do not invite this. In fact, as I’ve already said and will soon explain, I view it as a meaningless debate. Worse, it’s a distraction from what we should be debating. Intentional or not, it deflects the public’s attention from what’s really at issue.

Few ideas have more profoundly poisoned the minds of more people than the notion of a “free market” existing somewhere in the universe, into which government “intrudes.” In this view, whatever inequality or insecurity the market generates is assumed to be the natural and inevitable consequence of impersonal “market forces.” What you’re paid is simply a measure of what you’re worth in the market. If you aren’t paid enough to live on, so be it. If others rake in billions, they must be worth it. If millions of people are unemployed or their paychecks are shrinking or they have to work two or three jobs and have no idea what they’ll be earning next month or even next week, that’s unfortunate but it’s the outcome of “market forces.”

According to this view, whatever we might do to reduce inequality or economic insecurity—to make the economy work for most of us—runs the risk of distorting the market and causing it to be less efficient, or of producing unintended consequences that may end up harming us. Although market imperfections such as pollution or unsafe workplaces, or the need for public goods such as basic research or even aid to the poor, may require the government to intervene on occasion, these instances are exceptions to the general rule that the market knows best.

The prevailing view is so dominant that it is now almost taken for granted. It is taught in almost every course on introductory economics. It has found its way into everyday public discourse. One hears it expressed by politicians on both sides of the aisle.

The question typically left to debate is how much intervention is warranted. Conservatives want a smaller government and less intervention; liberals want a larger and more activist government. This has become the interminable debate, the bone of contention that splits left from right in America and in much of the rest of the capitalist world. One’s response to it typically depends on which you trust most (the least): the government or the “free market.”

But the prevailing view, as well as the debate it has spawned, is utterly false. There can be no “free market” without government. The “free market” does not exist in the wilds beyond the reach of civilization. Competition in the wild is a contest for survival in which the largest and strongest typically win. Civilization, by contrast, is defined by rules; rules create markets, and governments generate the rules. As the seventeenth-century political philosopher Thomas Hobbes put it in his book Leviathan:

[in nature] there is no place for industry, because the fruit thereof is uncertain: and consequently no culture of the earth; no navigation, nor use of the commodities that may be imported by sea; no commodious building; no instruments of moving and removing such things as require much force; no knowledge of the face of the earth; no account of time; no arts; no letters; no society; and which is worst of all, continual fear, and danger of violent death; and the life of man, solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short.

A market—any market—requires that government make and enforce the rules of the game. In most modern democracies, such rules emanate from legislatures, administrative agencies, and courts. Government doesn’t “intrude” on the “free market.” It creates the market.

The rules are neither neutral nor universal, and they are not permanent. Different societies at different times have adopted different versions. The rules partly mirror a society’s evolving norms and values but also reflect who in society has the most power to make or influence them. Yet the interminable debate over whether the “free market” is better than “government” makes it impossible for us to examine who exercises this power, how they benefit from doing so, and whether such rules need to be altered so that more people benefit from them.

The size of government is not unimportant, but the rules for how the free market functions have far greater impact on an economy and a society. Surely it is useful to debate how much government should tax and spend, regulate and subsidize. Yet these issues are at the margin of the economy, while the rules are the economy. It is impossible to have a market system without such rules and without the choices that lie behind them. As the economic historian Karl Polanyi recognized, those who argue for “less government” are really arguing for a different government—often one that favors them or their patrons.* 

* In his book The Great Transformation (1944) Polanyi argued that the market economy and the nation-state should be viewed as a single man-made system he called the “Market Society.” In his view, the coming of the modern nation-state and the modern capitalist economies it fostered altered human consciousness, from one based on reciprocity and redistribution to one based on utility and self-interest.

“Deregulation” of the financial sector in the United States in the 1980s and 1990s, for example, could more appropriately be described as “reregulation.” It did not mean less government. It meant a different set of rules, initially allowing Wall Street to speculate on a wide assortment of risky but lucrative bets and permitting banks to push mortgages onto people who couldn’t afford them. When the bubble burst in 2008, the government issued rules to protect the assets of the largest banks, subsidize them so they would not go under, and induce them to acquire weaker banks. At the same time, the government enforced other rules that caused millions of people to lose their homes. These were followed by additional rules intended to prevent the banks from engaging in new rounds of risky behavior (although in the view of many experts, these new rules are inadequate).

The critical things to watch out for aren’t the rare big events, such as the 2008 bailout of the Street itself, but the ongoing multitude of small rule changes that continuously alter the economic game. Even a big event’s most important effects are on how the game is played differently thereafter. The bailout of Wall Street created an implicit guarantee that the government would subsidize the biggest banks if they ever got into trouble. This, as I will show, gave the biggest banks a financial advantage over smaller banks and fueled their subsequent growth and dominance over the entire financial sector, which enhanced their subsequent political power to get rules they wanted and avoid those they did not.

The “free market” is a myth that prevents us from examining these rule changes and asking whom they serve. The myth is therefore highly useful to those who do not wish such an examination to be undertaken. It is no accident that those with disproportionate influence over these rules, who are the largest beneficiaries of how the rules have been designed and adapted, are also among the most vehement supporters of the “free market” and the most ardent advocates of the relative superiority of the market over government. But the debate itself also serves their goal of distracting the public from the underlying realities of how the rules are generated and changed, their own power over this process, and the extent to which they gain from the results. In other words, not only do these “free market” advocates want the public to agree with them about the superiority of the market but also about the central importance of this interminable debate.

They are helped by the fact that the underlying rules are well hidden in an economy where so much of what is owned and traded is becoming intangible and complex. Rules governing intellectual property, for example, are harder to see than the rules of an older economy in which property took the tangible forms of land, factories, and machinery. Likewise, monopolies and market power were clearer in the days of giant railroads and oil trusts than they are now, when a Google, Apple, Facebook, or Comcast can gain dominance over a network, platform, or communications system. At the same time, contracts were simpler to parse when buyers and sellers were on more or less equal footing and could easily know or discover what the other party was promising. That was before the advent of complex mortgages, consumer agreements, franchise systems, and employment contracts, all of whose terms are now largely dictated by one party. Similarly, financial obligations were clearer when banking was simpler and the savings of some were loaned to others who wanted to buy homes or start businesses. In today’s world of elaborate financial instruments, by contrast, it is sometimes difficult to tell who owes what to whom, or when, or why.

Before we can understand the consequences of all of this for modern capitalism, it is first necessary to address basic questions about how government has organized and reorganized the market, what interests have had the most influence on this process, and who has gained and who has lost as a result. To do so, we must examine the market mechanism in some detail.

There’s a lot happening in the world.  Through it all, Marketplace is here for you. 

You rely on Marketplace to break down the world’s events and tell you how it affects you in a fact-based, approachable way. We rely on your financial support to keep making that possible. 

Your donation today powers the independent journalism that you rely on. For just $5/month, you can help sustain Marketplace so we can keep reporting on the things that matter to you.